Category Archives: Quantative Easing

The “Even Greater” Depression of 1990 to 2019

As the saying goes, “it is a recession when it happens to others and a depression when it happens to you.”

In the last “Great” Depression from 1929 to 1945, Americans were well aware of the pain and misery that was wrought on the nation.  There are even some who wrongly claim that the only reason the United States got out of the “Great” Depression was World War II.  Debates aside, below is a percentage change chart of the Dow Jones Industrial Average from 1929 to 1954, the period of time that it took for the index to get back to “break even.”

image

There is no debate among the average American or Harvard economist about when the last “Great” Depression occurred in the United States.  However, when the exact same thing happens to one of our allies, it seem difficult for even the most esteem experts on the “Great” Depression to recognize the current depression simply because it isn’t happening to us.

That ally is Japan. To put our claim in context, we will show you the stock market of Japan as represented by the Nikkei 225 Index in exactly the same format as the Dow Jones Industrial Average above.

image

Someone please tell us that what Japan is going through isn’t a depression. We use the stock market as the most accurate real-time reflection of the economy, politics, and social well being, which is nothing new to long-time readers of our work.

Let’s reflect for a moment, in Japan from 1989 to 2008:

  • interest rates have been in decline
  • quantitative easing has been applied
  • banks that were among the top 6 of 10 in 1989 are now either defunct or merged into each other

How is it possible, that a key measure of the health of a nation like Japan could suffer so much and not be recognized to be in an “Even Greater” Depression?

Look at the Dow Jones Industrial Average from 1929 to 1954 again.  It took 25 years for the index to break even.  Now look at the Nikkei 225 Index, it has already been 29 years and the index is still –40% below the prior peak.

Let’s take a brief refresher course on what was said of Japan prior to the decline of 1990, this from the Dow Theory Letters as published by Richard Russell and dated May 12, 1989:

image

Or how about the following, dated October 18, 1989:

image

And this from November 29, 1989:

image

And finally, this from April 5, 1989:

image

It is not an uniquely American attribute to forget the past but to blithely walk past the “Even Greater” Depression within our midst while it impacts our ally is a brewing storm.

Investors, politicians, and citizens alike would do well to note the exact same (subtle and not so subtle) slights and invectives being lobbed around today.  Meanwhile, due diligence is necessary to first acknowledge the plight of an ally and act in the interest of both nations before it is too late.

Quantitative Easing: Addition by Subtraction

What is Quantitative Easing?

“Quantitative easing (QE), also known as large-scale asset purchases, is an expansionary monetary policy whereby a central bank buys predetermined amounts of government bonds or other financial assets in order to stimulate the economy and increase liquidity. An unconventional form of monetary policy, it is usually used when inflation is very low or negative, and standard expansionary monetary policy has become ineffective (source).”

Does Quantitative Easing Work?

We don’t think quantitative easing works.  We think that if it works then there should be evidence to support this ideas, little or none exists.  Japan was the “first” country to implement the modern version of quantitative easing in 2001.  That didn’t result in the same outsized change in the Japanese stock market.

However, some people believe very strongly in the idea that central bank policy in the form of quantitative easing meaningfully affects the economy and liquidity.  Surprisingly, the believers are not just fans of central bank intervention but also critics of the existence of central banks. 

What Happens When Quantitative Easing Ends?

Fans of central bank intervention suggest that Quantitative Easing ends when the economy and liquidity has been “restored.”  The assumption is that everything is alright and the economy will chug along as it “should.”

Critics of central banks say the stock market and economy will suffer without quantitative easing.  The view is that, since the market increase was due solely to Federal Reserve “stimulus” then without the injections, interest rate will climb and the stock market should collapse.

While we’re not lined ups as fans of central bank intervention, we believe the critics, mentioned above, are also sorely mistaken in their theory.

A Picture Worth Considering

In an article titled “The Rise and (Eventual) Fall in the Fed’s Balance Sheet” there is a chart depicting the historical level of the Federal Reserve Balance Sheet relative to nominal GDP. The chart, as seen below, potentially implies that, the contraction of the Federal Reserve balance sheet could be the biggest and best thing for the economy and liquidity of the markets.

image

Interpretation

The last peak in the Federal Reserve balance sheet, relative to nominal GDP, was in the period from 1937-1940.  In that period (‘37-‘40), interest rates bottomed out and started a long march to peak in 1981.  Also in that time, from 1940 to 1981, the Dow Jones Industrial Average ranged from a low of 42.42 on April 28, 1942 to a high of 1,051.70 on January 11, 1973 (+2,379.25%).

Also worth noting is the minor decline in the Fed balance sheet relative to nominal GDP from 1917 to 1929.  In  that period, the Dow Jones Industrial Average increased from 69.29 on December 24, 1917 to 380.33 on August 30, 1929 (+448.89%).

The critics of punch bowl economics might be surprised when they find that the exact opposite is likely to happen when the Federal Reserve attempts to reduce their balance sheet AND interest rates increase.  History suggests that taking away the “punch bowl” actually improves conditions for greater market stability and liquidity, for a while at least.  Sometimes, less is more.

QE3: A Blunt Object with Dull Impact

On September 13, 2012, the Federal Reserve issued a statement (found here) that an additional round of quantitative easing (QE3) was going to be the preferred method for monetary policy going forward.  The  QE3  would be in the form of $40 billion of monthly purchases of agency backed mortgage securities.  The rationale for this policy implementation was explained to be put in place to ensure maximum employment and price stability.  We wonder whether a natural state of maximum employment has already been achieved.  After all,  isn’t it always at the maximum level?

It is necessary to put the implementation of QE3 into perspective.  The first official pronouncement of QE took place on November 24, 2008.  At that time, the stock market, as reflected by the Dow Jones Industrial Average, had already declined –37.66% from the October 2007 high.  The deployment of QE1 at the time resulted in a temporary bounce and then the stock market proceeded to complete the decline to the March 2009 low, an additional decline of –26%. A -26% decline as if there was no effort on the part of the Federal Reserve to stabilize the situation, speaks volumes of the relative ineffectiveness of such a policy.

The second iteration of QE took place in early November 2010.  At the time, the Dow Jones Industrial Average was already in an established rising trend (+75% above the March 2009 low) and tacked on an additional +11.94%, to the April 2011 peak.  After the April 2011 peak, the Dow Jones Industrial Average declined –15.91%.  The implementation of QE2 in 2010 was nearly 5% above the October 3, 2011 low.  Does billions of dollars of money thrown at the economy suggest that it was worth the stagnant or mild gains in the economy?

As we’ve said in our January 2011 article titled “Federal Reserve Isn’t to Blame for the Current Market Run,” and as demonstrated by the relatively mild gains and/or declining returns as represented by the Dow Jones Industrial Average, whenever monetary policy has been put in place, quantitative easing has little impact on the expected outcome for where the stock market and economy will go.  Additionally, we've shown how in periods when the Federal Reserve didn't exist (1864-1913), the stock market would routinely rebound 50% to 100% of prior losses.

Why do we make comparisons between the stock market and Federal Reserve policy when actions taken by the Fed are intended to affect economic activity and not the stock market?  The answer lies in a 2004 paper, co-authored by Ben Bernanke before he became Fed chairman, titled “Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero Bound: An Empirical Assessment” which is THE basis for quantitative easing in the United States.  On page 8 of the 113 page document, step one for effective QE (out of three) is stated as follows:

“..using communications policies to shape public expectations about the future course of interest rates…[1]”

This is significant because the stock market is the court of public opinion on all matters relating to current and future economic expectations.  Dow Theory, a 110-year old approach to interpreting the stock market, has the following to say on this matter:

“The Averages Discount Everything — The fluctuations of the daily closing prices of the Dow-Jones rail and industrial averages afford a composite of all the hopes, disappointments, and knowledge of everyone who knows anything of financial matters, and for that reason the effects of coming events (excluding acts of God) are always properly anticipated in their movements.[2]”

All initial communications by the Federal Reserve are meant to sway the public and is voted on by the stock market either rising or falling in acceptance or rejection of the Federal Reserve’s communiqué. The book by Benjamin Graham titled Security Analysis highlights the point that the market is an arena where votes are cast in the following quote:

“The stock market is a voting machine…[3]”

We believe that the Federal Reserve decides exactly how much they have to follow through with their “communication policies” based on the magnitude of the reaction from the financial markets.

For us to believe that quantitative easing is an effective tool in the court of public opinion and ultimately for the economy, we'd like to see both the Dow Jones Industrial Average and Dow Jones Transportation Average to exceed previous all-time highs on the news.  Unfortunately, the latest announcement has not catapulted both indexes to new highs which, according to Dow Theory, puts the latest policy initiative in question.

Although there is little to demonstrate that monetary tools being put in place, like quantitative easing, are actually effective, what we are seeing is an emerging trend in when the Federal Reserve decides to take action.  In the chart below we see that when the percentage change from a year ago of real gross domestic product (GDP) has peaked, the Federal Reserve will attempt to take steps to stop the declining trend of GDP.

image

Keep in mind that since QE2, real GDP growth has still managed to trend lower than the period before, on a percentage basis.  This is not the ideal outcome of massive amounts of “liquidity” being “created.”  As can be seen in the chart above, the overall trend in year-over-year (y-o-y) percentage growth in real GDP has reflected a pronounced declining trend in alignment with the peaks of 2000 and 2004.  However, in the entire history of collected y-o-y percentage growth in real GDP, since 1947, the declining trend has been well established and should not be considered a new phenomena.

The fact that QE2 could not demonstrate y-o-y growth greater than the 2010 peak before QE3 was implemented suggests that the stock market and economy are easily susceptible to a major “shock” in spite of the Federal Reserve’s best efforts.  An additional takeaway from our interpretation is that, unless under “emergency conditions,” the Federal Reserve Bank will implement massive amounts of renewed quantitative easing if real GDP appears to have peaked as was the case shortly before the QE3 announcement on September 13, 2012.

[1] Ben S. Bernanke, Vincent R. Reinhart, and Brian P. Sack. “Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero Bound:
An Empirical Assessment.” Federal Reserve Bank, Washington D.C. 2004. PDF found here.

[2] Rhea, Robert. The Dow Theory. 1932. Barron’s Publishing, page 19.

[3] Graham, Benjamin. Security Analysis. 1934. page 452. found here.